John Maynard Keynes

Lectures in Moscow
(Sep 14-15, 1925)

John Maynard Keynes

 

___________________________________________________________

"THE ECONOMIC POSITION OF ENGLAND"

&

"THE ECONOMIC TRANSITION IN ENGLAND"

by John Maynard Keynes

(1925)

___________________________________________________________

 

back
Back

John Maynard Keynes  traveled to the USSR in 1925 to represent Cambridge University at the Bicentennial Celebrations of the Russian Academy of Sciences, held in Leningrad and Moscow between 5 and 14 September, 1925. Keynes gave two lectures in Moscow on "The Economic Position in England" (September 14) and "The Economic Transition in England" (September 15). It was printed in  Donald Moggridge (ed), 1981, The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes, Volume XIX, Activities 1922-1929, The Return to Gold and Industrial Policy, in two volumes, Part I, London: Macmillan, First Lecture: pp.408-411; Second Lecture: pp.438-442]

[Note on HET version: This version does not contain pagination as we have not obtained a copy of the original version of the lectures.   As far as we know, this essay is in the public domain. You are free to make use of this electronic version in any way you wish, except for commercial purposes, without asking permission. All comments and corrections of this text are encouraged. Click here for the original PDF version.]


 

THE ECONOMIC POSITION OF ENGLAND (September 14)

 

l. Money wages in England are 80 per cent higher than before the War. The cost of living of the working classes is 73 per cent higher. Thus real wages have improved about 4 percent. Since working hours have been somewhat reduced, and since the intensity of work is also-according to most observers-less rather than more, the position of the working class is improved.

2. At least this is the case for those who are in work. The black spot is the large proportion of unemployment. From 10 to 12 per cent of the workers are without employment, including near 1 million adult male workers. Even the position of these, however, is much better than it would have been in similar circumstances before the War; for a married unemployed worker receives from the state about 40 roubles a month.

3. The unemployment is not equally distributed throughout industry, but is concentrated in those trades which compete for their markets with foreign goods-in particular shipping, shipbuilding, coal, iron and steel, engineering and textiles. In those industries which depend on the home market and supply goods to satisfy the very considerable purchasing power of the working classes, the position is entirely satisfactory. For example, in the building industry the whole of the productive capacity is employed; and the tobacco industry, the beer industry, the artificial silk industry (which makes the stockings which every English factory-girl and shop-girl now wears) are making greater profits than ever before.

4. The explanation of this situation is the obvious one-with sterling at gold parity, British prices and wages are too high relatively to world prices. I reckon that British wages would have to fall nearly 20 per cent to be in equilibrium with those in France, Germany, Italy and Belgium, and nearly 10 per cent to be in equilibrium with the world situation as a whole. The problem how to bring about this reduction is as much a political as an economic problem. Not much progress has been made as yet towards its solution.

5. The result is that the industries of the country fall into two groupswhat are called the `sheltered' industries which are exceedingly prosperous and comfortable and the `unsheltered' industries which are in great distress. The high prices of the goods produced by the prosperous `sheltered' industries make wages and other costs in the `unsheltered' industries so high that the latter are handicapped in competition with their foreign rivals.

6. This disequilibrium between the two groups is the fundamental problem for Great Britain; and this problem has been gravely aggravated by the restoration of the gold standard. A year ago sterling was 12 per cent depreciated compared with gold, and this depreciation provided a sort of bounty to the export industries. Now, when sterling is at par, the ‘sheltered’ industries maintain the same prices and wages, whilst the ‘unsheltered’ industries, which sell for export, realise 12 per cent less in sterling for what they sell than they realised when sterling was depreciated. The result has been to reduce some of them almost to bankruptcy.

7. The correct remedy would be a fall of wages in the `sheltered' industries. But since employment is good in these industries and the trade unions strong and determined to accept no reductions, it is very difficult to put pressure on them. On the other hand, in the `unsheltered' industries, where the pressure of unemployment and bad trade exists in a high degree, the wages are already relatively low, so that these industries have a good case before public opinion and in justice for not suffering a further reduction.

8. The first example of an attempt to reduce wages-namely in the coal industry-has had a surprising result. This industry is the most exposed of all the ‘unsheltered’ industries. Accordingly the mine-owners were able to prove that if they continued to pay the present wages they would become bankrupt. On the other hand, the mine-workers were able to prove that, if the wages were lowered, their standard of life would be unjustly reduced below the standard in other industries. The other trade unions supported the mine-workers and declared that they would order an almost general strike if the Government insisted on the reduction. The Government, at a loss to know what to do, made the surprising decision to appoint a Commission to examine the case, and meanwhile for the Government themselves to pay the difference between what the mine-owners offer and what the mineworkers demand! This costs the Government at present about 20 million roubles a month.

9. The disequilibrium naturally results in brisk imports and reduced exports, thus impairing the balance of payments. This is being temporarily remedied by the Bank of England in two ways-partly by bank credits from America, and partly by prohibiting the financiers of the City from making new foreign loans. This prohibition now extends even to loans to other parts of the British Empire. This state of affairs also has its reaction on Russia and makes impossible what would in any case be difficult, namely new loans to Russia.

10. There is one other aspect of the case which has its application to Russia, namely the growth of population. The high level of unemployment and the difficulty in transferring labour out of the unprosperous industries into the prosperous industries is not a little due to the excessive growth of population and to the fact that the number of younger workers entering industry every year is much greater than the number of old workers going out. I believe that the poverty of Russia before the War was due to the great increase in population more than to any other cause. The War and the Revolution reduced the population. But I am told that now again there is a large excess of births over deaths. There is no greater danger than this to the economic future of Russia. There is no more important object of deliberate state policy than to secure a balanced budget of population.

11. In conclusion I emphasise that the economic problem of England is essentially a problem of solid and economic disequilibrium and not primarily a problem of poverty or of a lack of technical capacity to produce wealth.

___________________________________________________________
 

THE ECONOMIC TRANSITION IN ENGLAND (September 15)

Great Britain, not less than Russia, is suffering an economic transition in the early stages of which we are now living. An American economist, Professor Commons, one of the first to recognise the nature of this transition, distinguishes three epochs, three economic orders, upon the third of which we are entering.

The first is the epoch of scarcity, whether due to inefficiency or to violence, war, custom or superstition. In such a period there is the minimum of individual liberty and the maximum of communistic, feudalistic or governmental control through physical coercion. This was, with brief intervals in exceptional cases, the normal economic state of the world up to (say) the sixteenth or seventeenth century.

Next comes the era of abundance. In a period of extreme abundance there is the maximum of individual liberty and the minimum of coercive control through government; and individual bargaining takes the place of rationing. During the eighteenth and early nineteenth centuries Europe won its way out of the bondage of scarcity into the free air of abundance, and in the latter nineteenth century this epoch culminated gloriously in England in the victories of laissez-faire and historic liberalism. It is not surprising or discreditable that the veterans of the Liberal Party cast backward glances on that easier age.

But England is now entering on a third era, which Professor Commons has called the period of stabilisation and has truly characterised as the actual alternative to Marx's communism. In this period, he says, there is a diminution of individual liberty, enforced in part by governmental sanctions, but mainly by economic sanctions through concerted action, whether secret, semi-open, open or arbitrational, of associations, corporations, unions and other collective movements of manufacturers, merchants, labourers, farmers and bankers.

The extremes of this epoch in the realm of government are Fascism on the one side and Leninism on the other. For my part, I accept neither. Yet state socialism offers no middle course, because it also is sprung from the presuppositions of the era of abundance, just as much as laissez-faire individualism and the free play of economic forces. Therefore I direct all my mind and attention to the development of new methods and new ideas for effecting the transition from the economic anarchy of the individualistic capitalism which rules today in Western Europe towards a regime which will deliberately aim at controlling and directing economic forces in the interests of social justice and social stability. I still have enough optimism to believe that to effect this transition may be the true destiny of a New Liberalism.

It happens that England has today in the position of her coal industry an object lesson of the results of the confusion of ideas which now prevails. On the one side the Conservative Government is pursuing an orthodox nineteenth-century policy based on the assumption that economic adjustments can and ought to be brought about by the free play of the forces of supply and demand. They still assume that the things, which would follow on the assumption of free competition and the mobility of capital and labour, actually occur in the economic life of today.

On the other side not only the facts, but public opinion also, have moved a long distance away towards the epoch of stabilisation. The trade unions are strong enough to interfere with the free play of the forces of supply and demand; whilst public opinion, albeit with a grumble and with more than a suspicion that the trade unions are growing dangerous, supports the trade unions in their main contention that coalminers ought not to be the victims of cruel economic forces which they never set in motion.

The idea of the Conservatives, that you can, for example, alter the value of money and then leave the consequential adjustments to be brought about by the forces of supply and demand, belongs to the days of fifty or a hundred years ago when trade unions were powerless, and when the economic juggernaut was allowed to crash along the highway of progress without obstruction and even with applause.

The orthodox economics, which we have inherited from the nineteenth century, assumes a high degree of fluidity of the economic organism. It depends on what I would term the principle of diffusion — the principle that, when any disturbance is introduced at any point in the economic organism, it diffuses itself fairly rapidly through the whole organism until a new position of equilibrium has been reached. It has always been admitted that the economic organism is partly rigid and that friction may delay the process of diffusion. But it has been supposed that the organism has sufficient fluidity and mobility to allow the principle of diffusion to be a good working hypothesis.

That a great measure of diffusion still takes place, I do not deny. But the ease and rapidity of diffusion is-in England at least-much less than it used to be. I put this down to three main influences:

1. A rapidly progressive community possesses much more mobility than a stationary or slowly progressive community. In the case of the former equilibrium can be restored by (for example) a particular industry growing more or less fast. It is much easier to retard the rate of growth than actually to drive capital and labour, which are already in an industry, out of it. I attach immense importance to this. I do not think that Englishmen sufficiently realise to what an extent their nineteenth-century methods depended on the fact that the country was living in a continuing economic crescendo. The orthodox economic assumptions work much better in the United States than in England precisely because in the United States the crescendo of progress still continues.

2. The growth in the power and authority of the trade unions both to maintain wages and to exclude the entry of new labourers into a trade.

3. The growth of a sort of humanitarianism, exemplified in the 'dole' to the unemployed, which interferes with the natural pressure of economic forces on individuals.

These influences have, between them, introduced a considerable degree of rigidity into the British economic system. Yet the authorities still frame their policies on the assumption that a high degree of mobility and diffusion still exists. Hence our tears and troubles.

It is not an accident that our first difficulties, which will last long and take many different forms, should centre about monetary policy. For no feature of our pre-war system depended more fundamentally on the principle of diffusion than did our pre-war gold standard regulated by means of Bank rate. The first and most important step, in my judgement, is to establish a new monetary system based on a stable level of internal prices, which will not ask from the principle of diffusion more than it can perform.

But this is not the only item in my new economic programme. I believe that there are many other matters, left hitherto to individuals or to chance, which must become in future the subject of deliberate state policy and centralised state control. Let me mention two —(1) the size and quality of the population and (2) the magnitude and direction of employment of the new national savings year by year.

Some of you in Russia will not agree with me in seeking help in these matters from a reformed and remodelled Liberalism, which above all, shall not, if my ideal is realised, be a class party. Leninism — so it seems to me — is at the same [time] a persecuting religion and an experimental technique. Capitalism too is at the same time a religion, which is much more tolerant, however, than Leninism is, and a technique which, from having been experimental, is now perhaps in danger of becoming obsolescent. On the religious side it is not for me, who am a free-thinking heretic, to speak. But the experimental technique is necessarily a matter of most high interest. We in the West will watch what you do with sympathy and lively attention, in the hope that we may find something which we can learn from you. For we too have new problems to solve..

 

J. M. KEYNES
 

King's College, Cambridge

 

___________________________________________________________

 


 

  Home Alphabetical Index Schools of Thought  Essays & Surveys Texts Contact