Profile Major Works Resources

Antoine Augustin Cournot, 1801-1877

Portrait of Augustin.Cournot (click for larger image).

French philosopher, mathematician and economist, Augustin Cournot has been rightly hailed as one of the greatest of the Proto-Marginalists.  The unique insights of his major economics work, Researches into the Mathematical Principles of Wealth (1838) were without parallel.  Although neglected in his time, the impact of Cournot work on modern economics can hardly be overstated.

Augustin Cournot was born in the small town of Gray (Haute-Saône, Franche-Comte).  He was educated at local schools until he was fifteen. Thereafter, for the next four years, he worked haphazardly as a clerk in a lawyer's office.  Cournot directed his own studies throughout this time, concentrating mostly on philosophy and law.  Inspired by the work of Laplace, Cournot realized that he had to learn mathematics if he was to pursue his philosophical aspirations.  So, at the relatively ripe age of nineteen, Cournot enrolled in a mathematical preparatory course at a school in Besançon.  He excelled at it and subsequently won entry into the École Normale Supérieure (ENS) in Paris in 1821.  As it happens, the ENS was closed down in 1822 for political reasons and so Cournot transferred to the Sorbonne.  He obtained a licentiate in mathematics in 1823.  

During his student years in Paris, Cournot threw himself wholeheartedly into its stimulating intellectual and scientific atmosphere. He  attended seminars at the Academie des Sciences and the salon of the economist Joseph Droz. Among his main intellectual influences were Laplace and Lagrange.  Hachette, a former disciple of Condorcet, imbibed in him the principles of mathematique sociale, i.e. the idea that the social sciences, like the natural, could be dealt with mathematically.  Cournot counted the young mathematician Lejeune Dirichlet as a close friend.

From 1823, Cournot was employed as a literary advisor to Marshal Gouvoin Saint Cyr and a tutor to his son.  For the next ten years, Cournot would remain in Paris in this leisurely capacity, pursuing his studies and research at his own pace and in his own way.  In 1829, Cournot acquired a doctorate in sciences, focusing on mechanics and astronomy.  After Saint Cyr's death in 1830, Cournot took it upon himself to edit and publish the remaining volumes of his late employer's memoirs.  

Cournot's thesis and a few of his articles brought him to the attention of the mathematician Siméon-Denis Poisson who urged him to return to academia.  Cournot refused at first but, after his engagement with the Saint Cyr family ended in 1833, he took up a temporary appointment at the Academy in Paris.  It was during this time that he translated John Herschel's Astronomy (1834) and Dionysus Lardner's Mechanics (1835).

In 1834, through the good offices of Poisson, Cournot found a permanent appointment as professor of analysis and mechanics at Lyons.   A year later, Poisson secured him a rectorship  at the Academy of Grenoble.  Although his duties were mostly administrative, Cournot excelled at them.  In 1838, (again, at the instigation of the loyal Poisson), Cournot was called to Paris as Inspecteur Général des Études.  In that same year, he was made a Knight of the Légion d'honneur (he was elevated to an Officer in 1845).

In the same year he returned to Paris, Cournot published his economics masterpiece, the Recherches sur les principes mathématiques de la théorie des richesses (1838).  An outline of this treatise follows. 

Cournot begins with some preliminary remarks on the role of mathematics applied to the social sciences.  He announces that his purpose in using mathematics is merely to guide his reasoning and illustrate his argument rather than lead to any numerical calculations.  He acknowledges (and disparages) N.F. Canard as his only predecessor.  In his first three chapters, Cournot runs through the definition of wealth, absolute vs. relative prices and the law of one price.  

Then, in Chapter 4, he unveils his demand function. He writes it in general form as D = F(p).  He assumes that F(.) is continuous and takes it as an empirical proposition that the demand function is downward-sloping (the loi de débit, "law of demand").    It is important to note that Cournot's "demand function" is not a demand schedule in the modern sense.  His curve, D = F(p) merely summarizes the empirical relationship between price and quantity sold, rather than the conceptual relationship between price and the quantity sought by buyers. Cournot refuses to derive demand from any "utility"-based theories of individual behavior.  As he notes, the "accessory ideas of utility, scarcity, and suitability to the needs and enjoyments of mankind...are variable and by nature indeterminate, and consequently ill suited for the foundation of a scientific theory" (Cournot, 1838: p.10).  He satisfies himself with merely acknowledging that the functional form of F(.) depends on "the utility of the article, the nature of the services it can render or the enjoyments it can procure, on the habits and customs of the people, on the average wealth, and on the scale on which wealth is distributed." (1838: p.47).  He proceeds to draw the demand curve in price-quantity space (Fig. 1).  He also introduces the idea of "elasticity" of demand, but does not write it down in a mathematical formula.

In Chapter 5, Cournot jumps immediately into an analysis of monopoly.  Here, Cournot introduces the concept of a profit-maximizing producer.  He begins by positing a cost function  f(D) and discusses decreasing, constant and increasing costs to scale.  He shows, mathematically, how a producer will choose to produce at a quantity where marginal revenue is equal to marginal cost (he re-expresses marginal cost as a function of price in its own right, f'(D(p)) = y(p)).  In Chapter 6, he examines the impact of various forms of taxes and bounties on price and quantity produced, as well as their impact on the income of  producers and consumers.   

In Chapter 7, Cournot presents his famous "duopoly" model.  He sets up a mathematical model with two rival producers of a homogeneous product.  Each producer is conscious that his rival's quantity decision will also impact the price he faces and thus his profits.  Consequently, each producer chooses a quantity that maximizes his profits subject to the quantity reactions of his rival.   Cournot mathematically derives a deterministic solution as the quantities chosen by the rival producers are in accordance with each other's anticipated reactions.  Cournot showed how this equilibrium can be drawn as the intersection of two "reaction curves".  He depicts a stable and an unstable equilibrium in Figures 2 and 3 respectively. 

Comparing solutions, Cournot notes that under duopoly, the price is lower and the total quantity produced greater than under monopoly. He runs with this insight, showing that as the number of producers increases, the quantity becomes greater and the price lower.   In Chapter 8, he introduces the case of unlimited competition, i.e. where the quantity of producers is so great that the entry or departure of a individual producer has a negligible effect on the total quantity produced.  He goes on to derive the prices and quantities in this "perfectly competitive" situation, in particular showing that, at the solution, price is equal to marginal cost. 

In the remainder of his book, Cournot takes up what he calls the "communication of markets", or trade of a single good between regions.  In Ch. 10, he analyzes two isolated countries and one homogeneous product.  He shows that the impact of opening trade between the two countries leads to the equalization of prices, with the lower cost producer exporting to the higher cost country.  Cournot tries to prove that there are conditions where the opening of trade will lead to a decline in the quantity of the good and lower revenue.  He then proceeds to discuss the impact of import and export taxes and subsidies (and algebraic error here was spotted later by Edgeworth (1894)) .  On account of this, Cournot raises doubts in Chapter 12 about the "gains from trade" and defends the profitability of import duties.  

Finally, Cournot acknowledges that the solutions obtained via his "partial equilibrium" method are incomplete.  He recognizes the need to take multiple markets into account and trying to solve for the general equilibrium, but "this would surpass the powers of mathematical analysis" (Cournot, 1838: p.127). 

Cournot's 1838 work received hardly any response when it came out.  The denizens of the French Liberal School, who dominated the economics profession in France at the time, took no notice of it.  Cournot was left crushed and bitter.  In 1839, the sickly Poisson asked Cournot to represent him at the concours d'agrégation de mathématiques at the Conseil Royal.  After Poisson died in 1840, Cournot continued on at the Conseil as a deputy to Poisson's successor, the mathematician Louis Poinsot.   In 1841, Cournot published his lecture notes on analysis from Lyons, dedicating the resulting Traité to his long-time benefactor, Possion. 

 In 1843, Cournot made his first stab at probability theory in his brilliant Exposition.  He differentiated between three types of probabilities: objective, subjective and philosophical.  The former two follow their standard ontological  and epistemological definitions.  The third category refers to probabilities "which depend mainly on the idea that we have of the simplicity of the laws of nature." (1843: p.440) or what modern commentators would call "credal probabilities".

After the 1848 Revolution, Cournot was appointed to the Commission des Hautes Études.  It was during this time that he wrote his first treatise on the philosophy of science (1851).  In 1854, he became rector of the Academy at Dijon.  However, by this time, Cournot's lifelong eye-sight problem began getting worse.  In 1859, Cournot wrote his Souvenirs, a haunting autobiographical memoir (published posthumously in 1913).  Cournot retired from teaching in 1862 and moved back to Paris.

Despite the dark pessimism about the decline of his sight and his creative powers, Cournot wasn't quite yet finished.  He published two more philosophical treatises in 1861 and 1872 which sealed his fame in the French philosophy community.  But his reputation as an economist was lacking. Cournot took another stab with his Principes (1863), which, on the whole, was merely a  restatement of the 1838 Recherches  in more popular prose and without the mathematics.  Once again, it was completely neglected.  A Journal des économistes reviewer churlishly claimed that Cournot had "not gone beyond Ricardo", etc.  Cournot's resentment increased accordingly.

However, by this time the Marginalist Revolution had already started.  Léon Walras (1874), who had read Cournot's work early on, argued that his own theory was but a multi-market generalization of Cournot's partial equilibrium model (indeed, the notation is almost identical).  W. Stanley Jevons, who had not read him, nonetheless hailed him as a predecessor in later editions of his Theory (1871).  Francis Ysidro Edgeworth (1881) went to Cournot to pick up his theory of perfect competition.  Alfred Marshall claimed to have read him as far back as 1868, and extensively acknowledged Cournot's influence in his 1890 textbook, particularly in his discussion of the theory of the firm.  

Cournot lived long enough to greet the works of Walras and Jevons with a warm sense of vindication.  This is evident in Cournot's Revue sommaire (1877), a long, non-mathematical statement of his earlier work.  He seemed particularly grateful that Walras had bravely climbed the steps of the Institute de France and accused the academicians of injustice towards Cournot.  He died that same year. 

Tired of the complaints by Walras, Jevons and other young blades, the French mathematician Joseph Bertrand took it upon himself to finally provide the first review of the Cournot's Recherches (jointly with a Walras book) in the Journal des savants in 1883.  It was not a kind review.  Bertrand argued that Cournot had reached the wrong conclusion on practically everything, and reworked Cournot's duopoly model with prices, rather than quantities, as the strategic variables -- and obtained the competitive solution immediately.  Edgeworth (1897) revisited the model and assailed both Cournot and Bertrand for obtaining deterministic solutions, arguing that the equilibrium solution in the case of a small number of producers should always be indeterminate.

Cournot's Recherches were finally translated into English in 1898.  The introduction by Irving Fisher and Henry L. Moore's 1905 biographical pieces helped promote Cournot's work among Anglo-American economists.    The development of monopolistic competition in the 1930s drew much inspiration from Cournot's work (particularly after the "re-discovery" of Cournot's marginal revenue curve by R.F. Harrod).  

Cournot's influence grew by leaps and bounds in the second half of the 20th Century.  As game theory advanced, Mayberry, Nash and Shubik (1953) restated Cournot's duopoly theory as  a non-cooperative game with quantities as strategic variables.  They showed that Cournot's solution was nothing other than its "Nash equilibrium" (Nash, 1951).  Cournot's influence on modern theory continues unabated, having been given a particular boost in the attempt to develop non-cooperative foundations for Walrasian general equilibrium theory (e.g. Novshek and Sonnenschein (1978) and the 1980 JET Symposium).

 

  


top1.gif (924 bytes)Top

Major works of Augustin Cournot

  • Mémoire sur le mouvement d'un corps rigide: soutenu par un plan fixe, 1829 [bk]
  • Translator, Traité d'astronomie, par Sir John F.-W. Herschel, 1834. [bk]
  • Translator, Elémens de Mechanique by Henry Kater and Dionysus Lardner, 1835. [bk]
  • "Mémoire sur les applications du calcul des chances à la statistique judiciaire", 1838, Journal des mathématiques pures et appliquées, 12. T. 3. p.257-334. [pdf
  • Recherches sur les principes mathématiques de la théorie des richesses, 1838 [bk] [English transl. by N.T. Bacon1897, Researches into the Mathematical Principles of the Theory of Wealth [bk, Ch. 4 (pdf)]]
  • Traité élémentaire de la théorie des fonctions et du calcul infinitésimal, 1841.  v.1, v.2
  • Editor, Lettres de L. Euler à une princesse d'Allemagne sur divers sujets de physique et de philosophie,1842, v.1, v.2
  • Exposition de la théorie des chances et des probabilités, 1843. [bk]
  • De l'origine et des limites de la correspondence entre l'agèbre et la géométrie, 1847. [bk]
  • Essai sur les fondements de nos connaissances et sur les caractères de la critique philosophique, 2 vols, 1851, v.1, v.2
  • Traité de l'enchainement des idées fondamentales dans les sciences et dans l'histoire, 2 vols 1861, v.1, v.2
  • Principes de la théorie des richesses, 1863. [bk]
  • Des institutions d'instruction publiques en France, 1864. [bk]
  • Considérations sur la marche des ideées et des événements dans les temps modernes, 2 vols, 1872. v.1, v.2
  • Materialisme, vitalisme, rationalisme: Études des données de las science en philosophie, 1875.[bnf]
  • Revue sommaire des doctrines économiques, 1877. [bk]
  • Souvenirs, 1760-1860, 1913  [av]
  • A. A. Cournot, Oeuvres Complètes. 5 vols, 1973.

HET

 

top1.gif (924 bytes)Top

Resources on A. A. Cournot

19th Century

  • "La metaphysique d'inspiration et la metaphysique scientifique. MM. Dumesnil et Cournot", 1862, L'année littéraire et dramatique  [HET]
  • "Les questions d'actualité élevées à l'état de thèses scientifiques et de dogmes philosophiques -- MM. Cournot et J. Simon" 1865, L'année littéraire et dramatique  [HET]
  • "Review of Cournot's Considérations sur la marche des idées" by H. Chotard, 1872, Revue critique d'histoire et de littérature. [HET]
  • "Un Géomètre Philosophe: Antoine-Augustin Cournot" by Louis Liard, 1877, Revue des deux mondes.  [HET]
  • "MM. Cournot, Naudon, Boutrot", in  Paul Janet, 1879, La philosophie française contemporaine. [HET]
  • " Philosophes contemporains: M. Cournot" by T.V. Charpentier, 1881, Revue philosophique de la France et de l'étranger [HET]
  • "Théorie des Richesses: revue de Théories mathématiques de la richesse sociale par Léon Walras et Recherches sur les principes mathématiques de la théorie des richesses par Augustin Cournot",  by Joseph Bertrand, 1883, Journal des Savants [HET]
  • "Ravaisson on Cournot", in Félix Ravaisson, 1889, La philosophie en France au XIXe siècle, 1889, Paris: Hachette. [HET]
  • "Review of Cournot's Researches into the Mathematical Principles of Wealth" by F.D. Merritt, 1898, JPE [js]
  • "Le Hasard chez Aristote et chez Cournot" by Gaston Milhaud, 1902, Revue de métaphysique et de morale [HET]
  • "La philosophie sociale de Cournot" by Gabriel Tarde, 1903, Revue de métaphysique et de morale, p.207-30 [offprint]
  • "Une thèse de Cournot: l'histoire des sciences n'este-elle plus possible?", by F. Mentré, 1905, Revue de synthèse historique (v.11), p.1
  • Numéro spécialement consacré à Cournot, Société française de philosophie, Revue de métaphysique et de morale, 1905. 6. Année 13. Suppl (Editor: Max Leclerc): [HET page]
    • Front Matter [HET]
    • Henri Poincaré, "Cournot et les principes du calcul infinitésimal", p.293-306. [HET]
    • G. Milhaud, "Note sur la Raison chez Cournot", p.307-318 [HET]
    • Gabriel Tarde, "L'accident et le rationnel en histoire d'après Cournot", p.319-347 [HET]  [offprint]
    • C. Bouglé "Les rapports de l'histoire et de la science sociale d'après Cournot",  p.349-376 [HET]
    • Albert Aupetit, "L'oeuvre économique de Cournot",  p.377-393 [HET]
    • F. Faure, "Les idées de Cournot sur la statistique",  p.395-411 [HET]
    • A. Darlu, "Quelques vues de Cournot sur la politique", p.413-428 [HET]
    • Françisque Vial "Cournot et Enseignement", p.429-449 [HET]
    • D. Parodi, "Le criticisme de Cournot", p.451-484 [HET]
    • F. Mentré, "Les racines historiques du probabilisme rationnel de Cournot", p.485-508 [HET]
    • R. Audierne, "La classification des connaissances dans Comte et dans Cournot", p.509-519 [HET]
    • Henry L. Moore, "Antoine-Augustin Cournot", p.521-543 [pdf]
  • "Personality of Augustin Cournot', by Henry L. Moore, 1905, QJE [js]
  • "Note sure les oeuvres economiques d'Augustin Cournot", by Edgard Depitre, 1908, RHDES, p.187-96
  • "Review of F. Mentré, Cournot et la renaissance du probabilisme", by A. Penjon, 1909, Revue philosophique de la France et de l'étranger, 6 fasc.. Année 34.  p.67-75. [HET]
  • "Introduction" by E.-P. Bottinelli, 1913, Cournot's Souvenirs, [p.vi-xxxviii]
  • Cournot et la renaissance du probabilisme au XIXe siècle, by François Mentré, 1908 [bk]
  • Études sur Cournot by Gaston Milhaud, 1927 [bnf; HET]

Modern

 

 
top1.gif (924 bytes)Top
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

All rights reserved, Gonçalo L. Fonseca